You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
It follows that $\log {\widetilde M}_t \sim {\mathcal N} ( -\frac{t H \cdot H}{2}, t H \cdot H )$ and that consequently ${\widetilde M}_t$ is log normal.
975
975
976
-
### Simulating a Multiplicative Martingale Again
976
+
### Simulating a multiplicative martingale again
977
977
978
978
Next, we want a program to simulate the likelihood ratio process $\{ \tilde{M}_t \}_{t=0}^\infty$.
979
979
@@ -984,7 +984,7 @@ After accomplishing this, we want to display and study histograms of $\tilde{M}_
984
984
985
985
Here is code that accomplishes these tasks.
986
986
987
-
### Sample Paths
987
+
### Sample paths
988
988
989
989
Let's write a program to simulate sample paths of $\{ x_t, y_{t} \}_{t=0}^{\infty}$.
990
990
@@ -1257,7 +1257,7 @@ These probability density functions help us understand mechanics underlying the
1257
1257
* Enough mass moves toward the right tail to keep $E \widetilde M_T = 1$
1258
1258
even as most mass in the distribution of $\widetilde M_T$ collapses around $0$.
1259
1259
1260
-
### Multiplicative Martingale as Likelihood Ratio Process
1260
+
### Multiplicative martingale as likelihood ratio process
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/amss.md
+15-15Lines changed: 15 additions & 15 deletions
Display the source diff
Display the rich diff
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -61,7 +61,7 @@ In this lecture, we
61
61
62
62
We begin with an introduction to the model.
63
63
64
-
## Competitive Equilibrium with Distorting Taxes
64
+
## Competitive equilibrium with distorting taxes
65
65
66
66
Many but not all features of the economy are identical to those of {doc}`the Lucas-Stokey economy <opt_tax_recur>`.
67
67
@@ -118,7 +118,7 @@ AMSS allow the government to issue only one-period risk-free debt each period.
118
118
119
119
Ruling out complete markets in this way is a step in the direction of making total tax collections behave more like that prescribed in Robert Barro (1979) {cite}`Barro1979` than they do in Lucas and Stokey (1983) {cite}`LucasStokey1983`.
Equation {eq}`TS_gov_wo4a` must hold for each $s^t$ for each $t \geq 1$.
246
246
247
-
### Comparison with Lucas-Stokey Economy
247
+
### Comparison with Lucas-Stokey economy
248
248
249
249
The expression on the right side of {eq}`TS_gov_wo4a` in the Lucas-Stokey (1983) economy would equal the present value of a continuation stream of government net-of-interest surpluses evaluated at what would be competitive equilibrium Arrow-Debreu prices at date $t$.
250
250
@@ -254,7 +254,7 @@ In the AMSS economy, the restriction that government debt be risk-free imposes t
254
254
255
255
In a language used in the literature on incomplete markets models, it can be said that the AMSS model requires that at each $(t, s^t)$ what would be the present value of continuation government net-of-interest surpluses in the Lucas-Stokey model must belong to the **marketable subspace** of the AMSS model.
256
256
257
-
### Ramsey Problem Without State-contingent Debt
257
+
### Ramsey problem without state-contingent debt
258
258
259
259
After we have substituted the resource constraint into the utility function, we can express the Ramsey problem as being to choose an allocation that solves
260
260
@@ -286,7 +286,7 @@ and
286
286
287
287
given $b_0(s^{-1})$.
288
288
289
-
#### Lagrangian Formulation
289
+
#### Lagrangian formulation
290
290
291
291
Let $\gamma_0(s^0)$ be a non-negative Lagrange multiplier on constraint {eq}`AMSS_44`.
292
292
@@ -316,7 +316,7 @@ That would let us reduce the beginning-of-period indebtedness for some other his
316
316
317
317
These features flow from the fact that the government cannot use state-contingent debt and therefore cannot allocate its indebtedness efficiently across future states.
318
318
319
-
### Some Calculations
319
+
### Some calculations
320
320
321
321
It is helpful to apply two transformations to the Lagrangian.
322
322
@@ -408,7 +408,7 @@ tags: [collapse-20]
408
408
To analyze the AMSS model, we find it useful to adopt a recursive formulation
409
409
using techniques like those in our lectures on {doc}`dynamic Stackelberg models <dyn_stack>` and {doc}`optimal taxation with state-contingent debt <opt_tax_recur>`.
410
410
411
-
## Recursive Version of AMSS Model
411
+
## Recursive version of AMSS model
412
412
413
413
We now describe a recursive formulation of the AMSS economy.
414
414
@@ -424,7 +424,7 @@ We now explore how these constraints alter Bellman equations for a time
424
424
$0$ Ramsey planner and for time $t \geq 1$, history $s^t$
425
425
continuation Ramsey planners.
426
426
427
-
### Recasting State Variables
427
+
### Recasting state variables
428
428
429
429
In the AMSS setting, the government faces a sequence of budget constraints
430
430
@@ -487,7 +487,7 @@ history $s^t$ as
487
487
488
488
for $t \geq 1$.
489
489
490
-
### Measurability Constraints
490
+
### Measurability constraints
491
491
492
492
Write equation {eq}`eqn:AMSSapp2` as
493
493
@@ -510,7 +510,7 @@ That implies that it has to be *measurable* with respect to $s^{t-1}$.
510
510
Equations {eq}`eqn:AMSSapp2b` are the *measurability constraints* that the AMSS model adds to the single time $0$ implementation
511
511
constraint imposed in the Lucas and Stokey model.
512
512
513
-
### Two Bellman Equations
513
+
### Two Bellman equations
514
514
515
515
Let $\Pi(s|s_-)$ be a Markov transition matrix whose entries tell probabilities of moving from state $s_-$ to state $s$ in one period.
516
516
@@ -567,7 +567,7 @@ where maximization is subject to
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/amss2.md
+14-14Lines changed: 14 additions & 14 deletions
Display the source diff
Display the rich diff
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -88,7 +88,7 @@ import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
88
88
from scipy.optimize import fsolve, fmin
89
89
```
90
90
91
-
## Forces at Work
91
+
## Forces at work
92
92
93
93
The forces driving asymptotic outcomes here are examples of dynamics present in a more general class of incomplete markets models analyzed in {cite}`BEGS1` (BEGS).
94
94
@@ -112,7 +112,7 @@ rates rather than fluctuations in par values of debt to insure against shocks
112
112
shutting down the stochastic component of debt dynamics.
113
113
- At that point, the tail of the par value of government debt becomes a trivial martingale: it is constant over time.
114
114
115
-
## Logical Flow of Lecture
115
+
## Logical flow of lecture
116
116
117
117
We present ideas in the following order
118
118
@@ -126,7 +126,7 @@ We present ideas in the following order
126
126
- we verify that the LS Ramsey planner chooses to purchase **identical** claims to time $t+1$ consumption for all Markov states tomorrow for each Markov state today.
127
127
* We compute the BEGS approximations to check how accurately they describe the dynamics of the long-simulation.
128
128
129
-
### Equations from Lucas-Stokey (1983) Model
129
+
### Equations from Lucas-Stokey (1983) model
130
130
131
131
Although we are studying an AMSS {cite}`aiyagari2002optimal` economy, a Lucas-Stokey {cite}`LucasStokey1983` economy plays
132
132
an important role in the reverse-engineering calculation to be described below.
@@ -189,7 +189,7 @@ $$
189
189
It is useful to transform some of the above equations to forms that are more natural for analyzing the
190
190
case of a CRRA utility specification that we shall use in our example economies.
191
191
192
-
### Specification with CRRA Utility
192
+
### Specification with CRRA utility
193
193
194
194
As in lectures {doc}`optimal taxation without state-contingent debt <amss>` and {doc}`optimal taxation with state-contingent debt <opt_tax_recur>`,
195
195
we assume that the representative agent has utility function
@@ -244,7 +244,7 @@ The CRRA utility function is represented in the following class.
0 commit comments